1 00:00:10,740 --> 00:00:14,370 Hello, everyone, and welcome to the Oxford Martin School. 2 00:00:14,370 --> 00:00:21,930 My name's Charles Godfrey, I'm the director of the Oxford Martin School and we're here because of the visionary bequest by James Martin. 3 00:00:21,930 --> 00:00:30,270 I'm delighted to say that James widow, Jim Martens widow Lillian, is in the audience this afternoon with her daughter Gero, 4 00:00:30,270 --> 00:00:39,990 and I'm delighted to welcome our speaker, Diane Coyle, this afternoon in our series on evolving economic thought. 5 00:00:39,990 --> 00:00:45,750 Diane is currently the inaugural Bennett Professor of Public Policy and co-director of the Bennett Institute for 6 00:00:45,750 --> 00:00:54,390 Public Policy at the University of Cambridge and has been there about 15 months was previously at Manchester. 7 00:00:54,390 --> 00:00:59,820 Don has done a huge number of things, both in the academic world and in the public policy world. 8 00:00:59,820 --> 00:01:03,780 I'll just mention a couple of the things that Dan is involved at the moment. 9 00:01:03,780 --> 00:01:05,340 Member of the Natural Capital Committee, 10 00:01:05,340 --> 00:01:12,840 chaired by the town expert advice to the National Infrastructure Commission and a member of the very influential Council of Economic 11 00:01:12,840 --> 00:01:22,680 Advisers that was awarded a CVA in 2018 for contributions towards the public understanding of economics and how fields of public policy, 12 00:01:22,680 --> 00:01:27,870 economics, technology, industrial strategy and global inequality. 13 00:01:27,870 --> 00:01:36,210 And Dan is a fabulous author, and if you haven't read it, I do recommend GDP a brief but affectionate history, 14 00:01:36,210 --> 00:01:40,380 and it takes real skill to write so wonderfully on that topic. 15 00:01:40,380 --> 00:01:45,810 And I have to say I before I even read it, I was invited by the fact it doesn't have a picture of you in it, 16 00:01:45,810 --> 00:01:52,890 but it does have a picture of Utah cabbage who contributes not at all to GDP, but greatly to welfare. 17 00:01:52,890 --> 00:02:04,380 Sit down, please come and give your lecture. Good evening, everybody. 18 00:02:04,380 --> 00:02:10,710 My first challenge is to make sure I've got this the right way up because although I write about technology, I'm not very good at operating it. 19 00:02:10,710 --> 00:02:14,340 So hello all of you, and can you hear me properly at the back? 20 00:02:14,340 --> 00:02:23,130 OK. It's a great pleasure to be here today, and thank you very much for the invitation to take part in this series. 21 00:02:23,130 --> 00:02:32,430 And amongst my other interests, the state of economics has been one of them and I've been quite involved in the core curriculum project as well. 22 00:02:32,430 --> 00:02:35,020 And so I was delighted to accept the invitation, 23 00:02:35,020 --> 00:02:42,270 and I'm going to talk about my own work on digital technology, which I've been doing for many years now. 24 00:02:42,270 --> 00:02:51,690 In fact, my first book about it came out 22 years ago, and when I started getting interested in the mid 1990s and digital technology, 25 00:02:51,690 --> 00:02:55,650 I said to a very distinguished economist he was already very distinguished. 26 00:02:55,650 --> 00:03:00,270 He's now is more distinguished. I can't see him in the room this evening, but I'd better not name him. 27 00:03:00,270 --> 00:03:03,900 I said, the internet is wonderful. It's going to change all kinds of things. 28 00:03:03,900 --> 00:03:07,260 And he said, Why is the internet interesting? 29 00:03:07,260 --> 00:03:12,600 It's going to reduce transactions costs a bit, but we know how to handle transactions costs in our model. 30 00:03:12,600 --> 00:03:20,310 So why are you bothering wasting your time on this, on this new technology? And in a way that sets my theme this evening? 31 00:03:20,310 --> 00:03:25,350 Because what I want to argue is that the the characteristics, 32 00:03:25,350 --> 00:03:34,410 the economic characteristics of digital technology mean that the way we need to think about doing economics has to change. 33 00:03:34,410 --> 00:03:38,940 So that's the theme, and I'm going to start with this man. 34 00:03:38,940 --> 00:03:44,490 Some of you will know him. Hal Varian, chief economist at Google. 35 00:03:44,490 --> 00:03:51,510 And why does he lose sleep at night? And I ask this because I've heard him give a talk a couple of times, 36 00:03:51,510 --> 00:03:57,360 claiming that there is nothing to worry about in terms of competition in digital markets. 37 00:03:57,360 --> 00:04:02,460 Sure. Google has 98 percent of search outside China. 38 00:04:02,460 --> 00:04:06,660 It's quite a lot of it out of 100 percent, but there's nothing to worry about, 39 00:04:06,660 --> 00:04:12,600 he says, because any new technological upstarts that had a better search engine, 40 00:04:12,600 --> 00:04:20,340 better search technology could very quickly knock Google out of that position and grab that market for itself. 41 00:04:20,340 --> 00:04:24,390 And he says this is exactly what Google did to Yahoo back in the day. 42 00:04:24,390 --> 00:04:28,590 And so he loses sleep over, not over. 43 00:04:28,590 --> 00:04:32,310 Department of Justice investigations or European Commission investigations. 44 00:04:32,310 --> 00:04:40,290 But over the fear that the next Google is out there and it's going to eat the existing Google now. 45 00:04:40,290 --> 00:04:43,140 That's why he loses sleep. A lot of sceptics. 46 00:04:43,140 --> 00:04:49,170 There are a lot of sceptics about this claim, of course, and you might have heard the term gaffer or Google, 47 00:04:49,170 --> 00:04:53,820 Apple, Facebook, Amazon, Microsoft is sometimes there and sometimes not. 48 00:04:53,820 --> 00:04:57,810 Uber is sometimes there, but you can't make a nice acronym with Uber. 49 00:04:57,810 --> 00:05:05,940 So we call it gaffer and concerned about the dominance of digital companies in some of these markets has increased everywhere. 50 00:05:05,940 --> 00:05:10,440 European Commission has been particularly active in pursuing some of the cases, 51 00:05:10,440 --> 00:05:17,520 and the even the American antitrust authorities are now getting somewhat interested in it in this country. 52 00:05:17,520 --> 00:05:23,520 We had a digital competition expert panel chaired by Jason Furman, who's an economist at the Harvard Kennedy School, 53 00:05:23,520 --> 00:05:33,720 and I was a member of that as evidence of some trends towards concentration more widely in the US economy and maybe this one as well, 54 00:05:33,720 --> 00:05:41,160 but especially in digital, because these markets do tend to be dominated by one company. 55 00:05:41,160 --> 00:05:49,000 And there are reasons for that, and the reasons lie in the underlying economic characteristics of the technology. 56 00:05:49,000 --> 00:05:59,620 And these are what they are. First of all, superstar features, this superstar name came from a paper by Sherman Rosen in the early or mid 80s, 57 00:05:59,620 --> 00:06:06,280 where he was trying to explain the very high pay of a particular movie Star Wars food star. 58 00:06:06,280 --> 00:06:16,510 And it operates on the demand side and the supply side. On the supply side, there are very high fixed costs and very low or zero marginal cost. 59 00:06:16,510 --> 00:06:25,780 So increasing returns to scale and particularly depending on the level that those fixed costs, that that scale can be quite large. 60 00:06:25,780 --> 00:06:31,270 And on the demand side, you often talking about experience goods so people don't know what they're like until 61 00:06:31,270 --> 00:06:36,580 they have actually already consumed a movie watching a baseball match and so on. 62 00:06:36,580 --> 00:06:42,910 And so once people start to hear by word of mouth or other forms of contact that something is good, 63 00:06:42,910 --> 00:06:47,320 then even if by any objective characteristics is not better, 64 00:06:47,320 --> 00:06:53,500 particularly than anything else in the market, the demand will congregate on those particular suppliers. 65 00:06:53,500 --> 00:06:59,470 So those are the superstar features and they operate in these digital markets. 66 00:06:59,470 --> 00:07:06,130 They're also what are called indirect network effects in the jargon. Network effects are familiar for everyday life. 67 00:07:06,130 --> 00:07:11,190 If you want to make a phone call, then the more people on the phone network, the better it is for you. 68 00:07:11,190 --> 00:07:18,910 Indirect just refers to the fact that in many digital markets, they are matching suppliers to consumers. 69 00:07:18,910 --> 00:07:24,730 And so if you're a consumer of one of these goods, if you want to hire an Airbnb apartment, 70 00:07:24,730 --> 00:07:28,510 the more people supplying the Airbnb apartments, the better it is for you. 71 00:07:28,510 --> 00:07:34,270 And if you're a supplier who wants to rent out your apartment, the more consumers on the platform, the better it is for you. 72 00:07:34,270 --> 00:07:41,800 And so these indirect network effects are also mutually reinforcing and encouraging of scale. 73 00:07:41,800 --> 00:07:45,910 These platforms are very often matching their matching, quite varied supply, 74 00:07:45,910 --> 00:07:51,050 like the range of apartments that you can get in the city with quite varied demand. 75 00:07:51,050 --> 00:07:59,470 So they're quite heterogeneous and there's a matching offer going on there, and they have a particular price structure. 76 00:07:59,470 --> 00:08:07,300 If one side of the market is more likely to go to other suppliers, so usually it's the consumer side of the market. 77 00:08:07,300 --> 00:08:11,830 Then the other side has to subsidise them to stay on the platform. 78 00:08:11,830 --> 00:08:17,140 So many of these cases, consumers don't pay anything and supplies the platform, 79 00:08:17,140 --> 00:08:24,580 appetisers and search or apartment owners visiting their apartments, pay a commission or fee and a commission to the platform. 80 00:08:24,580 --> 00:08:32,590 So once one side subsidises the other, all of these mean there's what what's called the chicken and egg problem, which is exactly what it sounds like. 81 00:08:32,590 --> 00:08:36,130 It's really hard to get one of these platforms going and succeeding. 82 00:08:36,130 --> 00:08:43,180 And there's some new work out by Annabel GAWA and Michael Cusumano suggesting that as many as four and five platforms fail. 83 00:08:43,180 --> 00:08:48,580 I wouldn't be surprised if actually it was more than that. It's really hard to get to viable scale, 84 00:08:48,580 --> 00:08:59,090 and the big American ones have very large sums of venture capital money covering their losses for a long period, and those losses can be large indeed. 85 00:08:59,090 --> 00:09:03,430 And so all of this adds up to you need to be big. 86 00:09:03,430 --> 00:09:08,270 You've got to get to a certain critical mass. Once you do, there's a characteristic dynamic. 87 00:09:08,270 --> 00:09:13,810 So you've been bumping along for a while, you get to the critical point and then all of a sudden you're huge you. 88 00:09:13,810 --> 00:09:18,490 That takes off very quickly. And if you're not big, then you're dead. 89 00:09:18,490 --> 00:09:23,080 So those are the basic characteristics of these markets. 90 00:09:23,080 --> 00:09:30,610 So on the supply side, increasing returns to scale on the demand side that often experience good information goods. 91 00:09:30,610 --> 00:09:35,140 There are these large externalities in consumption in this form of these network effects. 92 00:09:35,140 --> 00:09:40,720 If you do basic economics, we focus on the externalities in production. But these are in consumption. 93 00:09:40,720 --> 00:09:48,160 There's great heterogeneity in the product. Every search is different or they're not, but you get the idea. 94 00:09:48,160 --> 00:09:49,990 And even in a competitive market, 95 00:09:49,990 --> 00:09:58,360 price is not going to equal marginal cost because marginal cost is so low and you've got to cover the fixed cost as well. 96 00:09:58,360 --> 00:10:02,260 So that's what they're like. There's the basics. 97 00:10:02,260 --> 00:10:08,330 There are also other features of these digital platforms that make it very hard to think about them, 98 00:10:08,330 --> 00:10:13,660 certainly in the competition context, in the way that you do any other kind of business. 99 00:10:13,660 --> 00:10:17,350 And one of this is the strategy called Envelopment. I love this. 100 00:10:17,350 --> 00:10:24,610 I took this picture in Manchester of Uber deliverers Uber Eats deliveries and Deliveroo deliveries, 101 00:10:24,610 --> 00:10:30,140 walking alongside each other as a form of healthy competition, obviously. 102 00:10:30,140 --> 00:10:37,550 So if you've got a lot of uses on one side of one market, if you've got a lot of consumers using your taxi service, 103 00:10:37,550 --> 00:10:45,080 which is what Uber is, then you can use those consumers to cross sell a completely different product. 104 00:10:45,080 --> 00:10:49,700 So this isn't quite like the bundling that we're used to in oligopolistic market and economics. 105 00:10:49,700 --> 00:10:55,190 The products have nothing to do with each other. It just happens to be that Uber decided in this case, 106 00:10:55,190 --> 00:11:02,180 it would get into the food delivery business because it had a lot of users already on its app, and that was easy. 107 00:11:02,180 --> 00:11:04,640 And so that means if you are thinking about competition, 108 00:11:04,640 --> 00:11:10,580 if a company is dominant in one market or a large animal market, you not only need to think about that market, 109 00:11:10,580 --> 00:11:19,070 you need to think about all the other ones that could get into and is scale is having a lot of uses, 110 00:11:19,070 --> 00:11:23,510 a bull market and a barrier to entry to other people getting into other markets. 111 00:11:23,510 --> 00:11:29,840 Or can you expect the dominant players to dive into anything that they think looks promising? 112 00:11:29,840 --> 00:11:35,270 Uber's latest thing is dark kitchens capitalising on the delivery market. 113 00:11:35,270 --> 00:11:43,580 They now want to buy up dark kitchens in big cities so that they can produce all different kinds of food and capture the whole supply chain there. 114 00:11:43,580 --> 00:11:50,540 So they do. That's very common. And the other thing that's really striking is the data barrier, 115 00:11:50,540 --> 00:11:57,440 and people sometimes call this the data flywheel or the data loop, and it's a self-reinforcing feedback mechanism. 116 00:11:57,440 --> 00:12:02,360 If you are a big company and you've got a great service, you get a lot of customers. 117 00:12:02,360 --> 00:12:10,490 If you have a lot of customers and you accumulate their data, you can use that data to improve your service and so it feeds on itself. 118 00:12:10,490 --> 00:12:19,300 And so one of the things that we looked at in our report was whether there are ways in particular to break down this data loop. 119 00:12:19,300 --> 00:12:30,440 But what all of these features add up to is that the kind of conventional analysis that we do in competition policy is much harder and in fact, 120 00:12:30,440 --> 00:12:38,600 it doesn't work at all because in a conventional competition enquiry and I spent eight years doing this and you look at 121 00:12:38,600 --> 00:12:46,700 the possibility for a merged company or a dominant company to increase its price by a small but significant amount. 122 00:12:46,700 --> 00:12:54,560 And you see what substitution possibilities that all can your customers easily switch to something that's very similar or not? 123 00:12:54,560 --> 00:13:02,150 And so it's called a snip test, which stands for small but significant. 124 00:13:02,150 --> 00:13:06,560 Increase in price, and I can't remember the instance for the minute. 125 00:13:06,560 --> 00:13:13,400 You can't do these in these markets, partly because you've got this phenomenon operating across different markets, 126 00:13:13,400 --> 00:13:19,910 so you need to figure out exactly what the boundaries of the markets that you're looking at. 127 00:13:19,910 --> 00:13:32,360 But also because of the asymmetry in price and a perfectly competitive platform may still be charging a zero price to its consumers. 128 00:13:32,360 --> 00:13:36,620 And so that standard kind of test is really difficult to do. 129 00:13:36,620 --> 00:13:44,400 An alternative would be to look at profitability, so the companies dominating a market, you would expect it to have higher than average profitability. 130 00:13:44,400 --> 00:13:52,670 And sometimes you do this analysis in an enquiry. But these are companies which even until they're very large, are losing money. 131 00:13:52,670 --> 00:13:57,970 So. It's a losing money and then charging zero prices, what's the problem? 132 00:13:57,970 --> 00:14:02,200 You have to ask as a competition analyst, why is that a problem at all? 133 00:14:02,200 --> 00:14:10,900 And there are these coaches that dynamics as well, that you're looking at potential competitors to a dominant company. 134 00:14:10,900 --> 00:14:15,220 And it's the Halliburton question, the Hal Varian challenge. You know, 135 00:14:15,220 --> 00:14:22,720 I'm really worried about this small guy because at some stage they could grow very quickly and capture this market conventional 136 00:14:22,720 --> 00:14:30,580 competition and don't handle these contexts very well and have never really handled the dynamics of markets really well. 137 00:14:30,580 --> 00:14:37,930 If you want to think about what the home of Google dominance might be, it's that there's innovation that's not going to happen because of it, 138 00:14:37,930 --> 00:14:41,800 that it will dominate the market such that the better search engine can't ever 139 00:14:41,800 --> 00:14:50,050 get into that market because of the data barrier or because of the sheer scale. 140 00:14:50,050 --> 00:14:52,870 So we've got to ask what the dynamic costs of this kind of dominance. 141 00:14:52,870 --> 00:14:58,510 And we are in a world not of static competition, which we're used to looking at in competition policy. 142 00:14:58,510 --> 00:15:09,790 But the world of sugar and competition, the creative destruction that he wrote about so famously and there are indeed examples of digital overthrow. 143 00:15:09,790 --> 00:15:17,020 So rather than look at competition in the market, we're looking at competition for the market in the terminology that will be introduced, 144 00:15:17,020 --> 00:15:22,900 and there hasn't been examples of this kind of overthrow. I've given you a chart here of Facebook. 145 00:15:22,900 --> 00:15:32,680 And if you look carefully, you'll see that actually it ends in 2014. So even before the recent Facebook scandals, there was some engagement metrics. 146 00:15:32,680 --> 00:15:39,940 This suggests that Facebook has passed its peak and may not be the dominant social media platform. 147 00:15:39,940 --> 00:15:48,370 And apparently, young people are using all kinds of things these days that we old folks sitting in this room have never even heard of. 148 00:15:48,370 --> 00:15:50,050 So maybe this will be the same. 149 00:15:50,050 --> 00:15:56,950 And there are earlier examples, too, like Microsoft Internet Explorer being the dominant browser and then being overturned, 150 00:15:56,950 --> 00:16:02,130 or as this chart shows, Facebook itself overthrowing MySpace. 151 00:16:02,130 --> 00:16:11,320 Look at MySpace. This deep research for this, and it turns out that Kim Kardashian is still on MySpace, so it isn't completely dead yet. 152 00:16:11,320 --> 00:16:16,810 But this kind of dynamic analysis is difficult for competition authorities to do 153 00:16:16,810 --> 00:16:22,270 because you have to think about what might happen to the sector in the future. 154 00:16:22,270 --> 00:16:28,000 You got to try to forecast the technology and the consumer response to that technology. 155 00:16:28,000 --> 00:16:32,080 So digital is different. It's got these increasing returns to scale. He's not alone. 156 00:16:32,080 --> 00:16:38,380 You need dynamics, these externalities. It's also a public good is it's not rivalry. 157 00:16:38,380 --> 00:16:44,770 In many cases, a piece of software is in technical terms of public good because once it's been written, 158 00:16:44,770 --> 00:16:51,820 it can be used by any number of people, and that doesn't detract from the first user. 159 00:16:51,820 --> 00:16:55,810 This is all a roundabout way of saying through the example of competition policy, 160 00:16:55,810 --> 00:17:03,040 that the conventional ways we have of thinking about production in the economy don't really apply in this sector. 161 00:17:03,040 --> 00:17:15,380 And for all that, academic economists do all kinds of research looking at digital companies and increasing returns to scale and so on. 162 00:17:15,380 --> 00:17:19,870 And they're not used in policy economics. The applied tools are not there yet. 163 00:17:19,870 --> 00:17:21,640 And we, as a research community, 164 00:17:21,640 --> 00:17:29,920 haven't given competition authorities the way to think about how do I know whether Facebook is really past his best and somebody 165 00:17:29,920 --> 00:17:38,230 else is coming in with a better search engine that in five years time might have 98 percent of the market and six billion users? 166 00:17:38,230 --> 00:17:52,040 We don't know how to answer that question. And a lot of what we revert to is our instinct about how markets operate doesn't apply and these markets. 167 00:17:52,040 --> 00:18:01,460 So this is one of an example of a general purpose technology, and they fulfil this definition. 168 00:18:01,460 --> 00:18:08,240 They enable radical innovation in both products and services and in processes of production. 169 00:18:08,240 --> 00:18:13,250 And these apply across a wide range of activities in the economy. They start out in a particular sector. 170 00:18:13,250 --> 00:18:16,580 And before you know it, they're applying to a wide range. 171 00:18:16,580 --> 00:18:23,270 They lead to a major reorganisation of the structure of the economy because they change input costs dramatically. 172 00:18:23,270 --> 00:18:27,440 They also require a lot of additional investments. So it's the same kind of dynamic. 173 00:18:27,440 --> 00:18:33,020 They start out very slowly. And then eventually they start to have quite dramatic impacts. 174 00:18:33,020 --> 00:18:40,610 And part of the reason for the slow start is micro-scale is because they need a lot of investments in infrastructure and organisation, 175 00:18:40,610 --> 00:18:42,800 in the skills to operate them and so on. 176 00:18:42,800 --> 00:18:51,950 So they're slow to diffuse the when really well known example of this is a paper Paul David wrote in 1980 about the spread of computer technology, 177 00:18:51,950 --> 00:18:57,590 digital technology and its first wave, comparing it to the electric dynamo. 178 00:18:57,590 --> 00:19:04,610 And he pointed out that that innovation had required new kinds of factories to be built because you 179 00:19:04,610 --> 00:19:09,800 only get the productivity benefits of using electricity to power the factory rather than steam. 180 00:19:09,800 --> 00:19:16,550 If you have low, flat factories with assembly lines rather than the tall ones, 181 00:19:16,550 --> 00:19:22,460 with the shaft being driven by one steam engine driving lots of machines on different stories of the building, 182 00:19:22,460 --> 00:19:29,510 so whole building's had to come along, the grid had to be built. The because the factories were in greenfield sites. 183 00:19:29,510 --> 00:19:37,700 Ultimately, you ended up with so suburbanisation and the electrification of the economy and the creation of household electronic goods. 184 00:19:37,700 --> 00:19:43,940 So that had an effect on women's activities and their ability to go out and work and paid employment. 185 00:19:43,940 --> 00:19:51,740 So the ultimate impacts were substantial, but the impact on real GDP growth. 186 00:19:51,740 --> 00:19:55,580 First of all, to the long time shows through in productivity figures. 187 00:19:55,580 --> 00:20:05,210 And even then, it was actually quite a small number. And the economic history looking at the GDP impact of general purpose technologies 188 00:20:05,210 --> 00:20:11,000 shows that it's not large numbers in terms of the increment to growth, 189 00:20:11,000 --> 00:20:14,720 but they have very dramatic impacts. So this is doing this, 190 00:20:14,720 --> 00:20:21,860 and before long it's going to be really stupid to talk about the digital economy and the ways that we wouldn't talk about the electricity economy. 191 00:20:21,860 --> 00:20:29,670 It just is the economy and you get the slow and fast pace of change. 192 00:20:29,670 --> 00:20:32,310 How dramatic is it going to be? Well, the answer is very, 193 00:20:32,310 --> 00:20:42,480 and to see that you need to look just at the prices and the top left panel here shows you the price of computation calculated by William, 194 00:20:42,480 --> 00:20:46,950 not a very well-known paper, and it's a log scale. 195 00:20:46,950 --> 00:20:55,800 So it shows you the issues in Moore's law because of that dramatic fall that begins around 1940. 196 00:20:55,800 --> 00:21:04,080 Most famously, that you get a doubling of the computing power or halving of the price every every 18 months or two years. 197 00:21:04,080 --> 00:21:12,060 How does that translate into actual prices? People pay for things. The other charts come from some of my recent research with co-authors, 198 00:21:12,060 --> 00:21:19,440 and the top right hand one is the price that you pay for access to cloud computing facilities. 199 00:21:19,440 --> 00:21:26,700 And you can see that it's come down quite dramatically in this chart, which runs from 2010 up to last year. 200 00:21:26,700 --> 00:21:35,580 This is not a log scale, but if you look at the figures, something that started out at 40 cents has is now less than 10 cents. 201 00:21:35,580 --> 00:21:39,960 And what this means is that companies that used to invest in servers and hire 202 00:21:39,960 --> 00:21:45,180 people to operate those and have I.T. departments don't need to do that now. 203 00:21:45,180 --> 00:21:53,340 If they've got one already, they might still have kept it. But more and more companies, pretty much all start ups, don't invest in their own servers, 204 00:21:53,340 --> 00:22:01,650 and they use cloud computing companies like Amazon Web Services or Microsoft Azure or Google's Cloud Services. 205 00:22:01,650 --> 00:22:07,470 You might recognise these names from the earlier part of my talk this evening. 206 00:22:07,470 --> 00:22:16,380 So it's cheap to do, and I have talked to executives who say, Well, we used to have this department and it cost tens of thousands of pounds a year. 207 00:22:16,380 --> 00:22:21,900 But now, if I want to do something, I put it on the company credit card and it's just a few pounds. 208 00:22:21,900 --> 00:22:26,880 So it's a dramatic fall in price, an increase in capability, 209 00:22:26,880 --> 00:22:36,300 and it means that companies don't need to have skilled data scientists to use A.I. they can use algorithms that are provided by these cloud providers. 210 00:22:36,300 --> 00:22:44,160 The second example is the price of telecommunications services. And the darkness runs from 2010 to 2015. 211 00:22:44,160 --> 00:22:56,400 We've updated it a bit pattern hasn't changed. The top line The Blue Line shows the official price index for telecommunication services over 212 00:22:56,400 --> 00:23:04,650 a period when communications technology has changed dramatically speeds the compression, 213 00:23:04,650 --> 00:23:14,130 the latency and the amount of data that people are using and transmitting have fundamentally changed over that period. 214 00:23:14,130 --> 00:23:21,930 So telecoms engineers came to own us and my colleagues and said, What is going on here? 215 00:23:21,930 --> 00:23:32,490 Why is this index showing no decrease in the price? And one answer was that the index left out new data services. 216 00:23:32,490 --> 00:23:41,940 So we put those in and that gives you the red line. So rather than having zero decrease, you get a decrease for third in the price over five years. 217 00:23:41,940 --> 00:23:46,440 And the bottom line, the purple one, shows a thought experiment of saying, 218 00:23:46,440 --> 00:23:52,080 Suppose we take the revenues of the companies and we divide that by the volume of data in bits, 219 00:23:52,080 --> 00:23:58,860 and that shows you a 90 percent decline over that five year period, and that's gone down even further since. 220 00:23:58,860 --> 00:24:04,800 And this is pretty logical thing to do because there will be bits of data. 221 00:24:04,800 --> 00:24:11,190 The component services actually do have different prices per bit, but they're converging quite rapidly, 222 00:24:11,190 --> 00:24:15,330 and the more they converge, the closer the price index will get to the purple line. 223 00:24:15,330 --> 00:24:24,690 So here too. You've got communications services falling substantially in price about 90 percent over a five year period. 224 00:24:24,690 --> 00:24:34,170 And so when things are almost free or really cheap, people use them a lot and that's what companies have been doing. 225 00:24:34,170 --> 00:24:38,190 I might maybe next and there's a lot of hype about A.I. 226 00:24:38,190 --> 00:24:43,080 There are many economists. I'm one of them who argue it's the next general purpose technology. 227 00:24:43,080 --> 00:24:47,400 It's not just more digital. There's a lot of hype about it. 228 00:24:47,400 --> 00:24:51,600 And you've probably seen things like this on the internet, 229 00:24:51,600 --> 00:25:01,030 which show you that it's actually really hard for a computer to distinguish between a chihuahua and a blueberry muffin. 230 00:25:01,030 --> 00:25:05,230 Actually, it's not that funny, because it turns out that for some specific tasks, 231 00:25:05,230 --> 00:25:10,900 including image recognition, the air has been better than we have since 2015. 232 00:25:10,900 --> 00:25:16,960 So this is one of the images. This is the image that competition and by 2015. 233 00:25:16,960 --> 00:25:21,190 The error rate for the algorithm is much lower and the error rate for humans. 234 00:25:21,190 --> 00:25:27,160 So it turns out that we're not very good at the blueberry muffin chihuahua test either. 235 00:25:27,160 --> 00:25:32,140 In fact, you can get some quite sophisticated algorithms for free. 236 00:25:32,140 --> 00:25:39,940 And I found a load of adverts for a code to build your own robot dogs. 237 00:25:39,940 --> 00:25:48,130 So these are this is number eight, 11 12 in the catalogue. As a teenager near you making robots like this right now. 238 00:25:48,130 --> 00:25:52,450 The parts are cheap, the algorithms are free. You can put them together. They will be roaming the streets. 239 00:25:52,450 --> 00:26:00,490 Folks are before we know it. So there is a lot of hype. The abilities of A.I. currently are quite narrow. 240 00:26:00,490 --> 00:26:04,450 But it's also really cheap and it's going to change again. 241 00:26:04,450 --> 00:26:10,150 Change what people do in some ways. That's not all. 242 00:26:10,150 --> 00:26:20,110 If you look at other areas outside the immediate digital territory like drug discovery, prices are falling faster there. 243 00:26:20,110 --> 00:26:25,450 And this is a chart from the National Institutes of Health showing that the costs of 244 00:26:25,450 --> 00:26:32,110 sequencing the genome are falling faster than predicted the trajectory of Moore's law. 245 00:26:32,110 --> 00:26:36,850 So this is like digital, but even more so, and this is a logarithmic scale. 246 00:26:36,850 --> 00:26:45,640 So this is really dramatic change in the price. And in a sense, drug discovery is becoming an AI technology. 247 00:26:45,640 --> 00:26:53,820 A lot of it's being done by A.I. All of this is about the production side of the economy and how that changes with digital. 248 00:26:53,820 --> 00:27:00,340 What about the consumption side? What about us? How do we feel about it? Is this how we feel about it? 249 00:27:00,340 --> 00:27:05,530 And judging by popular literature and a lot of the news? 250 00:27:05,530 --> 00:27:07,390 Yeah, we're pretty upset about this. 251 00:27:07,390 --> 00:27:17,650 And there are all kinds of stories about aling bias and the use of algorithms in the criminal justice system leading to undesired outcomes. 252 00:27:17,650 --> 00:27:24,580 But, you know, all new technologies make people afraid. And this is a cartoon from the age of electricity. 253 00:27:24,580 --> 00:27:30,670 And it wasn't Frankenstein in a vacuum. People were generally pretty sure that electricity was going to kill you. 254 00:27:30,670 --> 00:27:36,910 So here's somebody in Victorian London caught up in the wires and killed by the light. 255 00:27:36,910 --> 00:27:46,600 And so there's a fear about new technologies. And once people become familiar enough, they just can't get enough of them. 256 00:27:46,600 --> 00:27:49,990 And there's some work that's been done by Eric Brynjolfsson and his colleagues, 257 00:27:49,990 --> 00:27:59,590 and we're repeating this now for the UK and testing different methodologies about how much people really, really love digital technology. 258 00:27:59,590 --> 00:28:09,760 These are estimates of the willingness to accept giving up Facebook for a certain period of time or search engines or email. 259 00:28:09,760 --> 00:28:18,370 So this is probably too small to read search engines willingness to accept giving up all search engines for a year in 2016, 260 00:28:18,370 --> 00:28:23,050 almost $15000 or email almost $6000. 261 00:28:23,050 --> 00:28:27,310 I mean, some of us might pay to give up email, but we're not the average and so on. 262 00:28:27,310 --> 00:28:30,340 So it doesn't say that you can ask these up. 263 00:28:30,340 --> 00:28:37,600 It's not clear how you aggregate these or what kinds of time budget constraints you need to think about, which is what we want to explore. 264 00:28:37,600 --> 00:28:42,100 But these are big numbers. And if you could add them up, you'd have, I don't know, 265 00:28:42,100 --> 00:28:52,000 two thirds of median US income as the value that people say that they place on these technologies, just reflecting the fact that we use them a lot. 266 00:28:52,000 --> 00:28:59,710 So I'm not switching to UK data, but this is Ofcom's tracker of how much time people spend online. 267 00:28:59,710 --> 00:29:04,420 It goes from 2007 to 2017, and we are. 268 00:29:04,420 --> 00:29:12,790 The question is how many hours of a typical week would you say you spend online at home, at your workplace or place of education or anywhere else? 269 00:29:12,790 --> 00:29:19,360 So it's everything. It's looking at Twitter. When you're on your mobile phone answering emails at work, it's everything, 270 00:29:19,360 --> 00:29:30,410 but it's 24 hours a week online, so we're using it a lot and that's doubled over that 10 year period. 271 00:29:30,410 --> 00:29:41,960 So we're doing a lot of things online now we are doing banking, travel agency, education, entertainment, social media communication, 272 00:29:41,960 --> 00:29:54,110 accessing information as a syndrome and lot of what we would default to assuming about consumption of goods and services doesn't hold either, 273 00:29:54,110 --> 00:29:59,090 because if you think about the basic economic theory that we have our indifference curves. 274 00:29:59,090 --> 00:30:03,110 I was just a local school safety and I'm told they don't teach in different schools anymore. 275 00:30:03,110 --> 00:30:10,850 It's a sign of how old I am, but we have this construct of utility and individuals have utility derive from their preferences. 276 00:30:10,850 --> 00:30:15,500 We have seen think of some fixed preferences that are known in some way as I know, 277 00:30:15,500 --> 00:30:19,970 or we can figure it out from food preferences, from their behaviour. 278 00:30:19,970 --> 00:30:25,280 So we've got the utility concept and we aggregate individual utilities to get social welfare in some way. 279 00:30:25,280 --> 00:30:32,210 And there's a whole huge literature about how you might do that aggregation, but is the utility constraint? 280 00:30:32,210 --> 00:30:41,200 I've never seen the utility. I don't know what one is. This is a constraint that doesn't really allow for new goods and big changes in behaviour. 281 00:30:41,200 --> 00:30:49,040 And there's an assumption that we know now will we knew in 2005 when our preferences for buying smartphones was going to be? 282 00:30:49,040 --> 00:30:55,820 And that's obviously untrue. It's also not the case that preferences are individual and not fixed, 283 00:30:55,820 --> 00:31:01,730 and they're not an individual either, as these guys would have told you in the 1950s. 284 00:31:01,730 --> 00:31:10,820 The whole advertising industry is based on the malleability of preferences and also social influence and preferences. 285 00:31:10,820 --> 00:31:16,670 So the social aspect isn't just that there are network effects for some of these technologies, such as talking about before, 286 00:31:16,670 --> 00:31:22,280 but that people like Jony Ive persuade us that we really want an iPhone as a job 287 00:31:22,280 --> 00:31:31,710 category of YouTube influences and social media have become absolutely pervasive. 288 00:31:31,710 --> 00:31:38,520 I think, anyway, economics is in a bit of a mess about how we think about choice, and on the one hand, 289 00:31:38,520 --> 00:31:50,640 we assume that people are better than the A.I., the algorithms because we are assumed to optimise in the same way in a reasoning way. 290 00:31:50,640 --> 00:31:57,540 You can restrict information search for sure, but there's a rational calculation in some form going on, 291 00:31:57,540 --> 00:32:02,070 and we're better than the robots because they can only do it in their narrow domains in which they're programmed. 292 00:32:02,070 --> 00:32:06,330 Whereas we operate in one domains and on the other hand, you've got the behave. 293 00:32:06,330 --> 00:32:12,720 That's the standard economic assumption, and the competing behavioural assumption in effect assumes that we're not as smart 294 00:32:12,720 --> 00:32:17,730 as pigeons because there's a whole branch of study biological markers theory, 295 00:32:17,730 --> 00:32:31,590 which finds that creatures from even fungi to pigeons to monkeys, sea creatures or any creatures in certain contexts behave like rational, 296 00:32:31,590 --> 00:32:37,800 calculating individuals optimising in the information environment to which they find themselves. 297 00:32:37,800 --> 00:32:43,260 And yet, the behavioural economics assumes that we don't do that in lots of domains, 298 00:32:43,260 --> 00:32:50,100 so we don't really understand in which domains to apply which kind of model. 299 00:32:50,100 --> 00:32:52,010 So on the production side, 300 00:32:52,010 --> 00:32:59,700 are defaults set of assumptions and hold on the consumption side or default set of assumptions is a bit of a mess in this digital economy, 301 00:32:59,700 --> 00:33:02,850 which is becoming increasingly pervasive. 302 00:33:02,850 --> 00:33:09,000 And there's a sense in which economists know that, of course, we know that the economy is not like the Phillips machine. 303 00:33:09,000 --> 00:33:14,370 This is the Cambridge one. They they kinda opened the COVID doors so I could photograph it for you. 304 00:33:14,370 --> 00:33:16,920 We know that the economy is not like that. 305 00:33:16,920 --> 00:33:27,810 We've put the machine in the cupboard, but we haven't updated the everyday mental furniture in a really important sense. 306 00:33:27,810 --> 00:33:37,080 And it's in the sense a lot of public policy economics is based in some way on the basic welfare theorems in economics, 307 00:33:37,080 --> 00:33:42,540 and they are these people irrational, self-interested, Typekit fixed preferences. 308 00:33:42,540 --> 00:33:48,480 They use all the available information. There are no increasing returns to scale. 309 00:33:48,480 --> 00:33:57,420 There are no externalities. There are complete markets, including for future goods, good survival, not non-renewable. 310 00:33:57,420 --> 00:34:03,740 And they are owned by a stranger, their property rights and transactions can be enforced. 311 00:34:03,740 --> 00:34:09,540 And so from what I've been saying about digital markets, the digital economy, 312 00:34:09,540 --> 00:34:13,140 maybe the Russian self-interested, we don't have fixed preferences, though. 313 00:34:13,140 --> 00:34:20,790 Maybe we use all available information, but we've got increasing returns to scale across a really wide swathe of the economy, 314 00:34:20,790 --> 00:34:26,610 loads of externalities even more than we were used to thinking about in the old economy. 315 00:34:26,610 --> 00:34:33,260 We don't have complete markets for future goods, and many digital goods are non-removable. 316 00:34:33,260 --> 00:34:34,670 You might even question the last one, 317 00:34:34,670 --> 00:34:42,110 if you think about the contestation of intellectual property and the way that the concept of property and physical markets has 318 00:34:42,110 --> 00:34:51,380 been transferred to intangible intellectual property in digital markets and the some of the strange consequences of that. 319 00:34:51,380 --> 00:34:59,630 Now some economists in the room might be twitching now and saying, We know this is nothing new in this, and in a sense, that's absolutely true. 320 00:34:59,630 --> 00:35:04,880 There are lots of people in academic economics who know that these assumptions don't 321 00:35:04,880 --> 00:35:10,670 hold and are researching digital markets and increasing returns to scale and so on. 322 00:35:10,670 --> 00:35:15,360 But in public policy. They're not operating on the academic front here. 323 00:35:15,360 --> 00:35:21,360 They're operating on what they were taught in their courses. A number of years ago. 324 00:35:21,360 --> 00:35:26,430 And that matters because there are lots of economists in government. 325 00:35:26,430 --> 00:35:33,210 This is a Treasury chart going up to 15, you can see that lovely upward trend in the number of economists employed in the government economic service. 326 00:35:33,210 --> 00:35:36,330 I've put in a Red Cross to represent the Brexit surge. 327 00:35:36,330 --> 00:35:46,440 It's up to about 18:00 now, and a lot of other people who are not economists and government has studied some economics and they have internalised. 328 00:35:46,440 --> 00:35:52,980 They've been socialised into thinking in that conventional way, 329 00:35:52,980 --> 00:36:02,730 which ultimately says the default is that markets work that quotes free markets are the default way to organise the economy. 330 00:36:02,730 --> 00:36:11,040 And if you spot next another team, you can address that in an individual way and devise a government policy to fix it. 331 00:36:11,040 --> 00:36:15,450 So my argument is that the interdependence in the economy, 332 00:36:15,450 --> 00:36:23,970 which has always been there to some degree but is getting much greater thanks to digital, means that that should not be the default assumption. 333 00:36:23,970 --> 00:36:32,640 And we should switch it around. Well, Elmo wrote his Ph.D. thesis got published in 1950, and he made this very point. 334 00:36:32,640 --> 00:36:37,020 And actually a lot of what I do involves reading things people wrote in 1940 or 1950 and going, you know, 335 00:36:37,020 --> 00:36:42,210 they've really had a point with that simplifying premise that these types of 336 00:36:42,210 --> 00:36:48,030 interdependence in supply and demand a negligible or non-existent is misleading. 337 00:36:48,030 --> 00:36:51,210 Such an assumption is not neutral, he said. 338 00:36:51,210 --> 00:37:00,300 And he made this very point that the assumption that the absence of interdependence points you towards the benchmark free market model. 339 00:37:00,300 --> 00:37:06,270 And that's circular reasoning because you've assumed interdependence and therefore 340 00:37:06,270 --> 00:37:12,090 you conclude that markets of people operating you've assumed independence. 341 00:37:12,090 --> 00:37:17,220 So you conclude that markets people operating independently are the way to organise the economy. 342 00:37:17,220 --> 00:37:23,490 If you think about the interdependence, you might come to different types of conclusion. 343 00:37:23,490 --> 00:37:29,340 So I just want to think a bit about what it would mean to take economic welfare 344 00:37:29,340 --> 00:37:35,250 seriously and ditch that framework that we're all taught and our courses. 345 00:37:35,250 --> 00:37:39,450 And there are some really good straws in the wind, I think. 346 00:37:39,450 --> 00:37:45,840 So the top left hand one is an example from a fantastic paper in the Oxford Review of Economic Policy. 347 00:37:45,840 --> 00:37:56,190 I can see at least one of the co-authors here in the room, an example of using market design to take account of interdependencies at the start. 348 00:37:56,190 --> 00:38:00,810 So you're using a choice mechanism, a market process. 349 00:38:00,810 --> 00:38:06,480 But you are right from the start taking account of externalities and interdependencies and people's behaviour. 350 00:38:06,480 --> 00:38:11,010 So that's a very exciting area of research. 351 00:38:11,010 --> 00:38:19,860 The top right hand example comes from Jim O'Neill, who was appointed by the government to look at the problem of antimicrobial resistance. 352 00:38:19,860 --> 00:38:25,530 The report came out a couple of years ago, and it was praised by the pharmaceutical industry, 353 00:38:25,530 --> 00:38:32,400 which has since made absolutely zero progress on developing new generation antibiotics. 354 00:38:32,400 --> 00:38:38,100 And so early this year, Jim O'Neill came out and said the market is not going to do this. 355 00:38:38,100 --> 00:38:45,180 We need a public provider who will produce this kind of pharmaceutical product and that is 356 00:38:45,180 --> 00:38:52,680 taking the high fixed costs and the non-life rivalry of many of these types of good seriously. 357 00:38:52,680 --> 00:38:59,700 So I would argue that once there is a public policy we should be thinking about very seriously is public provision of digital goods. 358 00:38:59,700 --> 00:39:05,040 Why would we bother to leave it to Google and Facebook? Why would you not think about some public provision? 359 00:39:05,040 --> 00:39:09,540 Why would you not think about nationalising Facebook if only it were ours? 360 00:39:09,540 --> 00:39:16,200 So the characteristics that I start out by describing actually make public ownership, which of course has lots of problems. 361 00:39:16,200 --> 00:39:22,740 Public provision a very sensible alternative to think about bottom left hand corner 362 00:39:22,740 --> 00:39:29,700 is an Austrian and homework was about non-state non-market governance structures, 363 00:39:29,700 --> 00:39:39,540 institutional structures for dealing with the production and allocation, and exactly the kinds of goods that I've been talking about. 364 00:39:39,540 --> 00:39:44,910 Where trust is, trust needs to be high, when the goods are known rival, 365 00:39:44,910 --> 00:39:52,080 whether interdependencies between people and it's not a free market, it's not Whitehall telling you what to do. 366 00:39:52,080 --> 00:39:57,390 Maybe you should be thinking about different models of economic institutions. 367 00:39:57,390 --> 00:40:03,150 And then finally, and I can't resist talking about measurement, which is what I do in my day job. 368 00:40:03,150 --> 00:40:12,690 Thinking about economic statistics and GDP seems to me fundamentally the wrong measure anyway, 369 00:40:12,690 --> 00:40:20,220 because it's a value added construct and anybody who's done economics will know that you add up all the production in the. 370 00:40:20,220 --> 00:40:24,120 On me, all of the income, all expenditure, but on the production side, 371 00:40:24,120 --> 00:40:31,170 you edit all up and you net out the intermediate stages of consumption because the argument is you double counting. 372 00:40:31,170 --> 00:40:38,220 You don't want to count both the flour going into the bread and the bread at the same time. 373 00:40:38,220 --> 00:40:43,770 You've got a net out the intermediate products. What this means is that in a sense, 374 00:40:43,770 --> 00:40:50,310 the whole process of disintermediation and breaking up the value chains has gone on over the past 20 years and is 375 00:40:50,310 --> 00:40:58,530 continuing apace with things like cloud computing is sort of invisible in the statistics when letting it all out. 376 00:40:58,530 --> 00:41:05,220 The structure of the economy has changed in terms of those extended production chains has changed profoundly. 377 00:41:05,220 --> 00:41:14,310 And actually, that's what Adam Smith said. It was the driving force of capitalism that you the greater the scope of your market people to specialise. 378 00:41:14,310 --> 00:41:19,230 The more narrow the specialisation, then the better off it would be. 379 00:41:19,230 --> 00:41:26,940 And we've kind of taken that out. And so I'm very interested in thinking about just entirely different ways to think about what's making us better. 380 00:41:26,940 --> 00:41:34,230 How do we take account of those really high values? People seem to be placing on things that they do have to pay for, and that in some sense, 381 00:41:34,230 --> 00:41:40,590 don't get captured in a very obvious way in the GDP and conventional statistics. 382 00:41:40,590 --> 00:41:46,830 There's lots of stuff we're not measuring about the economy. We're not measuring how much consumers use these digital services, 383 00:41:46,830 --> 00:41:52,500 the time they spend and maybe a new time use survey that covers that, but it's not there yet. 384 00:41:52,500 --> 00:41:56,970 We don't know how many people use digital platforms they know, but we don't. 385 00:41:56,970 --> 00:42:05,010 We don't know the extent to which companies are adopting cloud computing. We know if they use any, but not how much or what services they using. 386 00:42:05,010 --> 00:42:09,960 We don't know how much companies are using AI. We don't know how much data there is. 387 00:42:09,960 --> 00:42:14,040 There's no data on data. Talks about it being a fundamental economic asset. 388 00:42:14,040 --> 00:42:20,760 I to right at the start about the way it was a barrier to entry in digital markets, 389 00:42:20,760 --> 00:42:27,450 but we didn't know what there is and we don't know how to value it, even if we didn't know what there is in terms of volume, in terms of bits of data. 390 00:42:27,450 --> 00:42:34,470 So I'm starting a project trying to think about how would you categorise the valuation of different types of data set? 391 00:42:34,470 --> 00:42:37,680 We have no idea about cross-border flows. 392 00:42:37,680 --> 00:42:47,310 If a manufacturer in this country emails a blueprint to a contract manufacturer in Malaysia, we don't know what the value of that is. 393 00:42:47,310 --> 00:42:52,080 We don't know what they're doing. We don't know what the transfer pricing is. We don't know how much data is crossing borders. 394 00:42:52,080 --> 00:42:56,220 If a company here uses a cloud computing service, 395 00:42:56,220 --> 00:43:00,540 we don't know if there's any export or import involved because we don't know we think the century goes to. 396 00:43:00,540 --> 00:43:06,750 It could be here in the UK or it could be in Belgium. We don't know what prices people are paying for things. 397 00:43:06,750 --> 00:43:10,020 The price of a digital camera is still recorded. 398 00:43:10,020 --> 00:43:14,910 Its weight in the consumer price index has been going down because people aren't buying them very much anymore. 399 00:43:14,910 --> 00:43:20,310 But nowhere are we putting the zero price that we're all paying for taking photographs and looking at them on our smartphone. 400 00:43:20,310 --> 00:43:28,020 So the price indices that we use to calculate real GDP and real productivity are completely wrong. 401 00:43:28,020 --> 00:43:30,000 We're not even doing some of the basics, 402 00:43:30,000 --> 00:43:44,460 and I thought I'd try to look up a trade in robots because robots are becoming thing and I found in the tariff schedule actually as a heading. 403 00:43:44,460 --> 00:43:47,700 Industrial robots, not elsewhere, specified or included. 404 00:43:47,700 --> 00:43:53,640 So if you're a car manufacturer and you've got a robot arm, you might describe it as a machine tool for making cars. 405 00:43:53,640 --> 00:43:58,140 If it's not specified anywhere else, you will put it in this category of industrial robots. 406 00:43:58,140 --> 00:44:07,560 We also count toy robots really carefully. We've got really good statistics on these little guys in the trade figures. 407 00:44:07,560 --> 00:44:13,410 And the reason is because non-human figures have different tariff rate than human figures. 408 00:44:13,410 --> 00:44:20,250 And it's been changed. That shows if you know the story that used to be human figures for toys versus animal figures for toys, 409 00:44:20,250 --> 00:44:25,980 and it was a famous court case fought over Star Wars characters and whether they were humans or animals. 410 00:44:25,980 --> 00:44:32,520 So the category is now being extended. For example, robots, devils or angels or aliens should be in that as well. 411 00:44:32,520 --> 00:44:40,140 So we don't have some quite basic stuff. So what's the new agenda for economics? 412 00:44:40,140 --> 00:44:45,960 We need some badly, need some policy and empirical approaches to these issues. 413 00:44:45,960 --> 00:44:52,230 Theoretically, the people research them, but the competition authority doesn't know how to do it. 414 00:44:52,230 --> 00:44:57,360 Somebody needs to start doing that applied work and figuring out, you know, 415 00:44:57,360 --> 00:45:04,250 what is the potential harm to consumers of a new search engine not being able to get into the market? 416 00:45:04,250 --> 00:45:07,710 And we need to think a lot about the public provision. 417 00:45:07,710 --> 00:45:16,650 As I was arguing an alternative the regulation of information goods, the public good and non rival the market will under provide them. 418 00:45:16,650 --> 00:45:20,150 How are we going to regulate this? How are we going to think about regulating and. 419 00:45:20,150 --> 00:45:26,780 Lateral property better. We need to think more about social capital and governance. 420 00:45:26,780 --> 00:45:35,360 As I was asking about Alan Ostrom was the right business models and governance and governance mechanisms for these types of companies. 421 00:45:35,360 --> 00:45:43,130 What do you think about the dynamics and what gets the economy onto one kind of dynamic rather than another? 422 00:45:43,130 --> 00:45:48,920 Both Shiller has an interesting book out this autumn called Narrative Economics, and it's exactly about this point. 423 00:45:48,920 --> 00:45:56,960 If you've got self-fulfilling phenomena or averting phenomena, what is it that tips you from one to the other determines which path you get onto? 424 00:45:56,960 --> 00:46:05,300 And the argument is, the narrative is part of the story. You've got to align people's behaviour, and the narrative is what helps to do that. 425 00:46:05,300 --> 00:46:11,450 And I think you really fundamentally in my mind about what is it that makes people better. 426 00:46:11,450 --> 00:46:16,970 We've got this wealth economic construct that actually we've known for a long time isn't fit for purpose and 427 00:46:16,970 --> 00:46:22,580 less and less so with the economic characteristics that are spreading across the economy through digital. 428 00:46:22,580 --> 00:46:30,660 So that would be my economic research agenda. So to sum up, we've got an economics that is all the things on the left, linear static, 429 00:46:30,660 --> 00:46:35,760 constant returns, et cetera, and an economy that's exactly the opposite. 430 00:46:35,760 --> 00:46:43,080 We've got a construct of economics, the point you towards the market thinking about the market as your default, your benchmark. 431 00:46:43,080 --> 00:46:48,330 Whereas we should be thinking about institutional structures as our benchmarks, 432 00:46:48,330 --> 00:46:56,850 whether that be market design or Ostrom style institutions or public provision, let's think seriously about institutional structures. 433 00:46:56,850 --> 00:47:05,310 This involves some changing of methods as well, and economists who hear about big data will always reply We we do. 434 00:47:05,310 --> 00:47:11,250 Data is what we do, and we might have not have millions and millions of records, but we've had a very large datasets. 435 00:47:11,250 --> 00:47:19,140 But there were new data sources. The digital economy itself is a source of data is quite hard to access the data generating process. 436 00:47:19,140 --> 00:47:24,930 The statistical properties aren't always well understood. A lot of it's held in these companies silos. 437 00:47:24,930 --> 00:47:30,030 We need to figure out how to get that through the top for the public good because there's public 438 00:47:30,030 --> 00:47:35,160 value being left on the table by the fact that these silos are completely separate from each other. 439 00:47:35,160 --> 00:47:42,090 I want to be able to join up my smartwatch and my shopping data online GDP data for my own purposes. 440 00:47:42,090 --> 00:47:48,000 I want something to find an app for me that does that matching and tells me how I can make myself better off. 441 00:47:48,000 --> 00:47:55,170 We need computational approaches. You can't do a lot of this and analytically the way that we've been used to in economics. 442 00:47:55,170 --> 00:48:01,470 So to give one example, we have people maximise their utility subject to budget constraint of money. 443 00:48:01,470 --> 00:48:07,710 If you want to add a budget constraint of time, which is key with these digital goods, it becomes algebraically intractable. 444 00:48:07,710 --> 00:48:14,400 You've got to do some other way when you reintroduce more economic history because we are in a technological 445 00:48:14,400 --> 00:48:21,600 revolution and looking back at past ones is a good way to think about how to approach the one we're going through. 446 00:48:21,600 --> 00:48:23,190 They'll be huge differences, 447 00:48:23,190 --> 00:48:32,010 but it points you towards thinking about those much more distant changes that I was talking about with the interesting example. 448 00:48:32,010 --> 00:48:38,790 I think narratives is an idea of really worth taking seriously. We have very quantitative and economics. 449 00:48:38,790 --> 00:48:42,420 I think we need to recognise the merits of qualitative methods. 450 00:48:42,420 --> 00:48:48,270 Going to talk to companies is absolutely illuminating and you find out lots of things about how they operate, 451 00:48:48,270 --> 00:48:53,430 and they've got no idea what their marginal costs are and don't know what you're talking about. 452 00:48:53,430 --> 00:48:57,720 But above all, I think it's a new mindset. It's a new default that we go to. 453 00:48:57,720 --> 00:49:01,650 And in this room, we can pat ourselves on the back if they're already thinking about this. 454 00:49:01,650 --> 00:49:05,200 But for the policy world, this is quite a big change in mindset. 455 00:49:05,200 --> 00:49:14,490 Still, too many economists in in government who who default to the market, as I said, I've been writing about this for a long time. 456 00:49:14,490 --> 00:49:18,900 This is just the advertising interlude at the end. 457 00:49:18,900 --> 00:49:26,010 So the way this world came out in 1997, and it's free on my website if anybody wants to read it and a lot of these issues, 458 00:49:26,010 --> 00:49:32,160 I think, were clear already back then the measurement issues, the sustainability issues I haven't really talked about. 459 00:49:32,160 --> 00:49:41,340 And a new book coming out early in 2020, which tries to apply some of the things I've been talking about this evening to public policy. 460 00:49:41,340 --> 00:49:48,120 And hopefully by the time we get to the next generation of students having their jobs and government, things will be a little bit different. 461 00:49:48,120 --> 00:50:02,100 Probably going a bit over my time. So I'm going to stop now. Thank you all very much. I think we've got a bit of time for Q&A. 462 00:50:02,100 --> 00:50:08,340 Just to remind you before questions, this is being videos I do remember when you ask a question that is going out live, 463 00:50:08,340 --> 00:50:14,080 who would like to ask the first question? Question there. 464 00:50:14,080 --> 00:50:21,040 Thank you so much for a great talk and for really focussing on an area that I think is we're going through such a transition. 465 00:50:21,040 --> 00:50:24,760 And I know in hindsight we'll look back and go, Wow, I can't believe we went through that, 466 00:50:24,760 --> 00:50:28,870 but you know, we didn't feel it while we were going through it. That's true generally, anyway. 467 00:50:28,870 --> 00:50:32,290 So we're moving from a tangible world to an intangible world. 468 00:50:32,290 --> 00:50:39,040 And one of the things that strikes me is economics is a huge thing and whether capitalism works and how it works within that, 469 00:50:39,040 --> 00:50:47,440 but it interacts with all these other things like laws. You're talking about IP laws and competition laws and things, taxation, right? 470 00:50:47,440 --> 00:50:52,690 And how we tax intangible assets versus tangible pensions, education systems, 471 00:50:52,690 --> 00:50:58,000 health care systems, they're all systems and they all interact and we can fix one. 472 00:50:58,000 --> 00:51:03,610 But if we do it in isolation of the others, we're going to have an asymmetry and it's not going to work. 473 00:51:03,610 --> 00:51:09,670 So how do you embed this into this greater kind of multi system? 474 00:51:09,670 --> 00:51:14,650 My goodness, if I had a quick answer to that, I'd be making a fortune from advising governments about it. 475 00:51:14,650 --> 00:51:16,300 It's obviously really hard. 476 00:51:16,300 --> 00:51:23,820 Any changing one system is hard, and we're in a context where we've got an overlapping set of systems, including the environmental system. 477 00:51:23,820 --> 00:51:30,070 And so one answer is that if you look back at the historical examples of what happens 478 00:51:30,070 --> 00:51:36,190 of conflict and period of chaos and contestation and quite a political conflict, 479 00:51:36,190 --> 00:51:41,500 and then eventually new arrangements and systems emerge out of that. 480 00:51:41,500 --> 00:51:47,500 The worry about apart from the discomfort of waiting for that this time is that some of 481 00:51:47,500 --> 00:51:52,550 those systems seem to be approaching catastrophic for the environment in particular. 482 00:51:52,550 --> 00:51:59,270 So you want to change the energy system pretty pronto. And I just don't know how you do it. 483 00:51:59,270 --> 00:52:02,950 It's really hard in government. We don't have government structures that enable it. 484 00:52:02,950 --> 00:52:06,100 When we did our report and the competition aspect of digital economy, 485 00:52:06,100 --> 00:52:16,240 we recommended a new regulatory body that would have particular oversight over companies deemed to have strategic market power at the same time. 486 00:52:16,240 --> 00:52:22,210 Frances Cairncross did a report on the news industry and the way it's been hollowed out by digital. 487 00:52:22,210 --> 00:52:27,640 And she recommended a new regulator. Ofcom already has some responsibilities. 488 00:52:27,640 --> 00:52:35,800 Competition and Markets Authority already has some responsibilities. DCMS put out a white paper saying, We need a regulator for online harms. 489 00:52:35,800 --> 00:52:43,090 You've already got six digital regulators there, and it's not at all obvious to me how Whitehall, 490 00:52:43,090 --> 00:52:48,250 never mind the Conservative Party that's in government at the moment, Will will settle on them. 491 00:52:48,250 --> 00:52:55,300 How will they arrange that and actually what is the vital management for that? So part of the question isn't about economics at all. 492 00:52:55,300 --> 00:53:02,680 It's about the political science fundamentally of what's the right level of governance for certain decisions and how do you do that? 493 00:53:02,680 --> 00:53:04,780 Joining up that we are profoundly bad at doing. 494 00:53:04,780 --> 00:53:09,430 We have government silos and I don't know how you bring this on is you've got to change the budget lines. 495 00:53:09,430 --> 00:53:13,480 It's tough. Thank you. Good, thank you, John. 496 00:53:13,480 --> 00:53:18,480 I've got a couple of questions that relate to the point that so much of what we buy now is free. 497 00:53:18,480 --> 00:53:22,450 Okay. The first one is what is the inflation rate generally in this environment? 498 00:53:22,450 --> 00:53:28,590 I know you've asked before. What does it mean for central bank policy? Should central banks be sending negative interest rates? 499 00:53:28,590 --> 00:53:32,250 But clearly, if they do that, the whole financial system doesn't work. 500 00:53:32,250 --> 00:53:37,590 On the other question relates to a similar theme, but basically, I saw some estimates coming out of the U.S., 501 00:53:37,590 --> 00:53:46,650 which said that if you try and value the internet and you put a user charge on it, the value of the internet is something like $500 billion. 502 00:53:46,650 --> 00:53:52,170 And to put that in context, world GDP is 80 on the value of the entire energy industry. 503 00:53:52,170 --> 00:53:56,610 20. So if that's true, surely geopolitics are going to come in here. 504 00:53:56,610 --> 00:54:01,440 Governments are going to try and grab this for taxpayers or to do something with it. 505 00:54:01,440 --> 00:54:04,650 Well, my government would love to start taxing some of this, 506 00:54:04,650 --> 00:54:13,350 but digital companies are just as good as any other multinational and moving their profits to places where they don't get taxed. 507 00:54:13,350 --> 00:54:18,420 So I'm not a macro economist and I'm no expert on what the Bank of England ought to be doing. 508 00:54:18,420 --> 00:54:21,930 We still have money. You can still count nominal GDP. 509 00:54:21,930 --> 00:54:31,590 And I think part of the error is to think not only that, you can calculate real GDP in a meaningful way given your point about price indices, 510 00:54:31,590 --> 00:54:36,210 but that you can then compare that to potential real GDP. 511 00:54:36,210 --> 00:54:43,560 I don't think we've got any idea really what what that is. For all of these intangible sectors. 512 00:54:43,560 --> 00:54:44,580 So if I were them, 513 00:54:44,580 --> 00:54:52,680 I would be looking at nominal GDP and actually I would be raising interest rates because the banking sector isn't functioning with low interest rates, 514 00:54:52,680 --> 00:54:59,670 never mind negative ones. And it point seatbelts, not using monetary policy as a means of demand management, I think at the moment. 515 00:54:59,670 --> 00:55:05,480 That was a huge caveat. That is probably 30 years since I've done any macroeconomics. 516 00:55:05,480 --> 00:55:18,300 Eric, terrific talk. Diane, as one of our leading experts on metrics, I'd like to ask you about a metric that policymakers obsess over productivity. 517 00:55:18,300 --> 00:55:25,560 You know, it has a clear meaning and is useful concept in a world of goods that you can draw upon your foot in this world. 518 00:55:25,560 --> 00:55:31,260 What does it mean? Does it mean anything? Do we need a new concept? We need a new way of thinking about that whole notion. 519 00:55:31,260 --> 00:55:38,010 I think you're right. We need a new concept, and the one that I've been playing with is about time. 520 00:55:38,010 --> 00:55:46,020 Because in a service based economy, never mind digital and intangible and a service based economy, you either want something to happen really quickly. 521 00:55:46,020 --> 00:55:50,940 You want your train to take you as fast as possible on the journey. 522 00:55:50,940 --> 00:55:56,040 You've got to have a blood test done. You want that to be done as quickly as possible or you want the opposite. 523 00:55:56,040 --> 00:56:00,300 You want it to be as long as it needs to be in really high quality. 524 00:56:00,300 --> 00:56:07,800 So if you're in the ICU, you want to have the devoted attention of a skilled nurse for 24 hours a day. 525 00:56:07,800 --> 00:56:11,670 So those would be examples of productivity. Not at all. Not at all. 526 00:56:11,670 --> 00:56:17,880 Captured by the current productivity metrics and services. So I think the concept needs to change and even physical goods, 527 00:56:17,880 --> 00:56:25,310 the quality change that gets embedded in those now means that it's very hard to think about what productivity figures need. 528 00:56:25,310 --> 00:56:33,220 Thank you. Over there, David. 529 00:56:33,220 --> 00:56:40,630 Hi, Dan, you managed to do the whole top without mentioning the greatest externality facing us, which obviously we need to think about pricing. 530 00:56:40,630 --> 00:56:43,780 We need to think about how we deal with it. It's a global problem. 531 00:56:43,780 --> 00:56:51,710 It's got huge numbers of and then I'd thought about consequences that would be happening over time. 532 00:56:51,710 --> 00:57:00,080 I mean, it's very hard to think that these are the key problems, given that we've got a much bigger problem overlying it. 533 00:57:00,080 --> 00:57:09,020 And I do wonder about how you would think about integrating climate change into your kind of analysis here. 534 00:57:09,020 --> 00:57:13,580 It's a good challenge, and I think about it in a separate mental bucket is the honest answer. 535 00:57:13,580 --> 00:57:20,120 So as well as trying to measure digital and GDP, I try to think about the balance sheet of the economy, 536 00:57:20,120 --> 00:57:24,530 including natural assets and the health of the climate. 537 00:57:24,530 --> 00:57:29,420 And so we have a programme looking at the moment of natural capital and social capital. 538 00:57:29,420 --> 00:57:35,810 And you know, if you don't have a balance sheet in some broad sense, you're not thinking about sustainability. 539 00:57:35,810 --> 00:57:39,020 It doesn't answer the detail of your question in any way. 540 00:57:39,020 --> 00:57:46,730 But if you think about it in terms of metrics, then thinking about assets seems to be one way to go about it. 541 00:57:46,730 --> 00:57:50,720 But you know, as you note, people in the room are much more expert than I am on this. 542 00:57:50,720 --> 00:57:59,660 A lot of thought has been going into thinking about policy approaches to solving the climate change problem. 543 00:57:59,660 --> 00:58:03,860 And it's not really an economic question, it seems to me now it's the political, again, 544 00:58:03,860 --> 00:58:11,480 a political science question about why it's so hard for any of those policies to gain traction. 545 00:58:11,480 --> 00:58:18,620 And the one that looks most appealing to every politician I've ever spoken to is that we find some wonderful new technology that fixes it. 546 00:58:18,620 --> 00:58:23,600 Don, one of the things I didn't say in my introduction is that you've been a member of the BBC Trust. 547 00:58:23,600 --> 00:58:29,930 Does the argument about the public provision of information and some of the digital goods? 548 00:58:29,930 --> 00:58:36,440 Does it have traction when applied to the BBC in policy circles in this country? 549 00:58:36,440 --> 00:58:41,060 Yes. And that's one of the experiences that informs my thinking about this and whether we 550 00:58:41,060 --> 00:58:46,820 should have a public service search engine or public service social media company. 551 00:58:46,820 --> 00:58:52,640 Because although the BBC has been attacked by free market politicians and funding has been cut, 552 00:58:52,640 --> 00:58:59,570 so that isn't the same solid consensus about it as I would have been 30 years ago. 553 00:58:59,570 --> 00:59:04,880 It's very popular, it's very high quality. Its services are really widely used. 554 00:59:04,880 --> 00:59:10,340 And I spent my eight years on the BBC Trust being concerned about its impact on the commercial market, 555 00:59:10,340 --> 00:59:15,920 and it's always been very careful not to foreclose markets to commercial rivals. 556 00:59:15,920 --> 00:59:20,840 But we've got a really healthy media market with a really big public player in it, 557 00:59:20,840 --> 00:59:29,330 and I think it means that the competition hasn't been about large number of viewers and the lowest common denominator programming. 558 00:59:29,330 --> 00:59:34,130 There's been competition about quality as well. And so an about innovation. 559 00:59:34,130 --> 00:59:39,860 We are one of the few net exporters of popular and classical music around the world. 560 00:59:39,860 --> 00:59:48,500 Sweden is one of the US is the other. And that's partly because we've got a public service broadcaster with a mission to encourage new material, 561 00:59:48,500 --> 00:59:52,970 new creation inside this country so that it gets done and then it gets exported. 562 00:59:52,970 --> 00:59:56,220 So I think it's a great parallel, actually. Thank you. 563 00:59:56,220 --> 01:00:02,390 Question over there. Yeah. You talked a lot about costs going down with these new technologies. 564 01:00:02,390 --> 01:00:06,860 My sense is that if you think of ICTs overall, 565 01:00:06,860 --> 01:00:12,650 then the household budget or individual budgets have just been steadily growing 566 01:00:12,650 --> 01:00:18,590 in terms of the amount of money that these services costs to individuals. 567 01:00:18,590 --> 01:00:23,870 And you also talked about kind of how we change this or how what kind of choices people make. 568 01:00:23,870 --> 01:00:28,880 It seems to me that that is not going to change. I mean, it's not going to increase vastly, 569 01:00:28,880 --> 01:00:34,460 but driving down the costs for these large parts of a household or individual 570 01:00:34,460 --> 01:00:38,750 budgets that have kind of grown over time isn't going to change anytime quickly, 571 01:00:38,750 --> 01:00:44,930 even if it's not going to go up very much. I think there are two things going on. 572 01:00:44,930 --> 01:00:50,540 One is that the price households pay per byte data. 573 01:00:50,540 --> 01:00:58,490 Has been going down substantially, but the amount of the budget that they spend on information goods has been rising. 574 01:00:58,490 --> 01:01:03,140 And that's the kind of shift in consumption patterns that we've seen over and over again over time. 575 01:01:03,140 --> 01:01:05,150 And you know, when people have low incomes, 576 01:01:05,150 --> 01:01:11,540 they spend more on food and shelter and that diversifies into other kinds of goods and then into other kinds of services. 577 01:01:11,540 --> 01:01:16,170 And so there's no reason to expect that that share will go down. 578 01:01:16,170 --> 01:01:21,640 But I think that's different from the price per byte of information, if you like. 579 01:01:21,640 --> 01:01:28,490 Distinguish between two of them. Thank you. Other any further questions, one, 580 01:01:28,490 --> 01:01:36,570 they can you can you make some comments on how this relates to our thinking about inequality in the sense that you know, 581 01:01:36,570 --> 01:01:38,750 the way a lot of this technology is working? 582 01:01:38,750 --> 01:01:45,900 On one hand, you're getting ever more billionaires and millionaires and a lot of the sort of wealth going towards them. 583 01:01:45,900 --> 01:01:51,650 And and but on the other hand, lots of poor people are getting access to lots of technology very, very cheaply. 584 01:01:51,650 --> 01:02:00,560 How do we sort of think about global inequality and the impact of all this discussion on the inequality we care about you? 585 01:02:00,560 --> 01:02:06,640 So, so clearly, these are both going on at the same time, access to goods plus plus and inequality. 586 01:02:06,640 --> 01:02:12,130 And so the short answer is it's complicated. 587 01:02:12,130 --> 01:02:16,210 One is that there are genuine things like superstar effects. 588 01:02:16,210 --> 01:02:21,340 So for some individuals, those will operate and make them very well off. 589 01:02:21,340 --> 01:02:34,070 That is also. A sort of locational phenomenon in that the digital economy is enhancing forces of geographic agglomeration into big cities. 590 01:02:34,070 --> 01:02:41,510 So productivity and incomes are higher in big cities, and that seems to be accelerating, at least if the US data is anything to go by. 591 01:02:41,510 --> 01:02:46,700 So that's happening. There's also the thing that we often overlook in the economic discussion, 592 01:02:46,700 --> 01:02:50,810 which is the politics of it and a lot of the inequalities is driven by politics, 593 01:02:50,810 --> 01:03:02,720 by tax cuts for the wealthy, by bashing the unions and weakening labour market power by all kinds of institutional structures that can be changed. 594 01:03:02,720 --> 01:03:07,730 And I have a Ph.D. student who's looking at exactly this issue about the difference in the incomes 595 01:03:07,730 --> 01:03:13,880 of workers who were in industrial jobs got downsized and how that compares to green countries. 596 01:03:13,880 --> 01:03:15,230 And it's very different. 597 01:03:15,230 --> 01:03:21,680 So we have in our heads that the US model, there's something kind of deterministic about what the technology and trade effects are doing. 598 01:03:21,680 --> 01:03:26,300 It gets refracted through politics as well, and that's a big part of the story, I think. 599 01:03:26,300 --> 01:03:36,950 Thank you, gentlemen in a blue jumper. You mentioned the importance or perhaps the new importance of economic history. 600 01:03:36,950 --> 01:03:45,170 I wonder whether there's any parallel or you can draw any between the the way in which public policy responded at the various stages of, 601 01:03:45,170 --> 01:03:54,770 say, the industrial revolution. I'm thinking, say, canals, speed, electricity, late 19th century when there's a lot of disarray about all of that, 602 01:03:54,770 --> 01:04:02,860 as you as you said, how quickly did public policy respond to that? 603 01:04:02,860 --> 01:04:11,830 It depends which bit you're talking about, and some of it was quite variable and some areas of deregulation, 604 01:04:11,830 --> 01:04:16,390 financial deregulation, financial changes and regulation seem to happen relatively quickly. 605 01:04:16,390 --> 01:04:21,760 Things like the limited liability company came in relatively early in the period. 606 01:04:21,760 --> 01:04:32,410 Things like safety, regulation or standards, which involve coordinating a lot of people in places much more slowly. 607 01:04:32,410 --> 01:04:40,090 The one interesting panel is the data collection, and it took a long time for the government to start collecting data on the 608 01:04:40,090 --> 01:04:45,790 industrial economy and for a very long period during the industrial revolution, 609 01:04:45,790 --> 01:04:51,650 there were fantastic agricultural statistics. But all of the information people had about the industrial economy child labour were 610 01:04:51,650 --> 01:04:55,930 number of mines and so on came through blue book reports commissioned by parliaments. 611 01:04:55,930 --> 01:05:03,160 They were sort of one-off reports on what was happening. So even for policymakers to understand what's going on by having statistics is pretty. 612 01:05:03,160 --> 01:05:11,890 It's pretty slow. The categories people have categories in, they had to collect the data and new technologies, often dangerous to start with. 613 01:05:11,890 --> 01:05:17,530 I showed the cartoons for electricity, but it was dangerous. Air travel was dangerous to start with. 614 01:05:17,530 --> 01:05:24,490 And I think an interesting question now is whether a tolerance for any kind of danger has reduced and whether autonomous vehicles will ever 615 01:05:24,490 --> 01:05:34,780 really happen outside quite tightly due fenced areas because we don't have a tolerance for machines killing people in the way that we used to. 616 01:05:34,780 --> 01:05:48,910 Thank you. That, Sarah. So thank you, Diana, for just a wonderful talk. 617 01:05:48,910 --> 01:05:56,380 Your slide of the 1500 civil servants in Britain that learnt and old economics, 618 01:05:56,380 --> 01:06:03,670 which you think can't address these, these problems, perhaps let alone the problems that David would add. 619 01:06:03,670 --> 01:06:07,030 How do you address that? I mean, obviously, they should all buy your book and read it. 620 01:06:07,030 --> 01:06:18,670 But but seriously, you you know you're Moore's law slides have their equivalent for the need for policy innovation to deal with this. 621 01:06:18,670 --> 01:06:26,590 So any ideas on on what we do with government? I think the training need isn't so much my new book or that. 622 01:06:26,590 --> 01:06:30,820 Of course, I hope we'll buy it as understanding the technologies that they're dealing with. 623 01:06:30,820 --> 01:06:37,000 And there's not a lot of expertise in even regulators on these technologies, 624 01:06:37,000 --> 01:06:43,180 and partly because the digital companies themselves buy so much of the expertise. 625 01:06:43,180 --> 01:06:47,530 I think it's about the climate of ideas more than targeting the individuals. 626 01:06:47,530 --> 01:06:55,540 And we've had a long period where a climate of ideas has been dominated by a free market benchmark. 627 01:06:55,540 --> 01:07:05,500 It was actually a process encouraged by certain economists and think tanks and embedded by the Thatcher and Reagan revolutions. 628 01:07:05,500 --> 01:07:09,340 And that has to change, I think, and I think it is, I see all kinds of straws in the wind. 629 01:07:09,340 --> 01:07:18,970 Maybe I'm a deluded optimist, but I think that is changing and that will cause all those policymakers to through social influence, 630 01:07:18,970 --> 01:07:25,050 change the way they think as well and reflect differently on the way they approach policy issues. 631 01:07:25,050 --> 01:07:30,990 Thank you. Before asking you to thank done again. Two announcements, first of all. 632 01:07:30,990 --> 01:07:35,130 Please join us for a glass of wine next door. In a moment. 633 01:07:35,130 --> 01:07:38,010 And also just a bit of advertising. 634 01:07:38,010 --> 01:07:46,920 Next week, we have a double act Colin Meyer and Paul Collier, both from Oxford, talking about the future of the corporation, economy and society. 635 01:07:46,920 --> 01:07:51,810 And the following week we have Eric Fine, hooker Eric. I don't know the title of your talk. 636 01:07:51,810 --> 01:08:02,100 Do you yet have new economic and moral foundations for the new moral and economic foundations for the Anthropocene? 637 01:08:02,100 --> 01:08:06,750 So please come along to both of them, but please join me now for thanking God. 638 01:08:06,750 --> 01:08:21,201 Thank you for the great.